Jurisprudence

This article was written by Srija Singh, a student at Amity Law School, Noida. This article discusses corn laws along with their origin and repercussions. The author has also discussed how and why it was repealed.

It has been published by Rachit Garg.

Introduction 

The revocation of Britain’s Sludge Laws in 1846, one of the most important profitable policy opinions of the nineteenth century, has long conspired and puzzled political scientists, chroniclers, and economists. Why would a Conservative High Minister act against his own party’s claims? The Rightists formed their government in 1841 with a strong commitment to defending husbandry. A year later, Prime Minister Sir Robert Peel was in charge of repealing the protectionist Sludge Laws, violating party beliefs and undermining the economic interests of land-keeping. Only a third of Conservative members of Parliament supported the abandonment of the legislation, and within a month of its repeal, Peel’s government fell. The Rightists remained out of control for decades. In this article, we will discuss the Corn Law and how it originated, and why it was repealed. 

Download Now

What is Corn Laws

The word “corn” is generally (but far from widely) held to mean the dominant original cereal crop. In the United Kingdom (UK), “corn” means either wheat or all traditional cereal crops (wheat, barley, oats, etc.). The Corn Laws were enacted in the United Kingdom between 1815 and 1846, imposing limits and duties on imported grain. They were intended to raise grain prices to help independent directors. The policies raised food costs and drew criticism from civic groups with far less political influence than in rural Britain. The Corn Laws had set up high import fees, making it prohibitively expensive to import garbage from other countries, even when food inventories were low. Conservative renters supported the measure, but it was opposed by Whig manufacturers (a member or supporter of a major British political group of the late 17th and early 19th centuries seeking to limit the royal authority and increase parliamentary power and workers). The Anti-Corn Law League was successful in transforming popular and elite opposition to the legislation into a huge, civil, middle-class moral movement with a romantic ideal.

The first two years of Irish scarcity, from 1845 to 1852, were marked by a significant lack of new food inventories. Sir Robert Peel, a conservative, was able to call off the war with the backing of the Whigs in Parliament, defeating the objections of most of his party.

“Corn” referred to any grain that needed ground, notably wheat. The Importation Act of 1815 enacted the laws which were repealed by the Importation Act of 1846. The statutes were sometimes seen as exemplifications of British mercantilism.

Food prices were profitable by-products. The price of grain was related to the price of the most essential primary food, chuck, and the worker spent a sizable part of his stipend on the chuck.

The result was a political schism between co-proprietors (a long-established class that was disproportionately represented in Parliament) and the growing class of manufacturers and fake employees (who were under-represented). The former demanded that their husbandry profits be maximized by raising the price at which their grain could be sold. The goal was to maximize profits by breaking the stipend they supplied to their plant workers; yet men could not work in the factories if a plant pay envelope was not enough to feed them and their families; so, high grain prices kept factory stipends high as well.

Origin of Corn Laws

In 1813, a House of Commons Committee vowed to ban foreign-produced grain until the price of domestically grown muck reached eighty shillings per quarter. The political economist Thomas Malthus thought this was an acceptable price and that relying on imported maize would be catastrophic for Britain because fewer charges would reduce sloggers’ stipends and manufacturers would lose money due to property owners and growers’ loss of bargaining strength. Nonetheless, David Ricardo believed in free trade, believing that Britain might make better use of its resources. Sludge prices ceased with the outbreak of peace in 1814, and Lord Liverpool’s Tory administration passed the 1815 Corn Law. This culminated in major riots in London as well as the Manchester Peterloo Massacre. In 1820, Thomas Tooke’s merchandisers’ petition was brought to the Commons, asking for free trade and the elimination of protective tariffs. Lord Liverpool said that he supported free trade but that the complex restrictions made it difficult to curb protectionist policies.

William Huskisson, President of the Board of Commerce, wrote the Commons Committee report in 1821 asking for a return to the “basically open” trade of 1815. The Importation Act of 1822 said that sludge might be imported if the price of domestically obtained sludge reached eighty shillings per quarter. Still, it could not be imported if the price fell below seventy shillings per quarter. The sludge price never reached eighty shillings between the passage of this Act and 1828. Property owners rejected Huskisson’s sliding scale idea in 1827, so Huskisson and the interim Prime Minister, the Duke of Wellington, devised a new sliding scale for the Corn Importation Act of 1828. When the price of residential sludge was fifty-two shillings and a quarter or less, the duty was thirty-four shillings and eight pence, reduced to one shilling when the price reached seventy-three shillings.

In 1820, Thomas Tooke presented the merchants’ petition to the House of Commons, requesting free trade and the repeal of protective tariffs. In 1821, the President of the Board of Commerce, William Huskisson, published a Commons Committee report calling for a response to the 1815 years of “almost unrestricted” trade. The Whig administrations who controlled from 1830 until 1941 chose not to repeal the sludge laws. Sir Robert Peel became Conservative Prime Minister in 1841, and for the first time, Richard Cobden, a famous free trader, was branded. Peel had studied Adam Smith’s workshop, David Hume’s workshop, and Ricardo’s workshop, and in 1839 said, “I have read all that has been published by the gravest experts on political frugality touching rent, stipend, taxes, and tithes.” In 1842, he altered the sliding tariff system, lowering the highest tariff rate to twenty shillings if the price fell to fifty-one shillings or less.

In 1838, the Thani-Corn Law League began secretly working for repeal. They paid for pens like William Cooke Taylor to explore their cause in northern England’s manufacturing districts. Cook Taylor was an anti-Corn Law propagandist who published several works, including the Natural History of Society (1841), Notes of a Tour in the Manufacturing Districts of Lancashire (1842), and Factories and the Factory System (1844). Cobden and the members of the anti-Corn Law League believed that inexpensive food meant an advance stipend, and Cobden praised a worker.

When nourishments are high, people have so little to pay for them that they have little or nothing left to buy clothes with; and when they have little to buy clothes with, there are many clothes sold; and when there are many clothes sold, there are too many to vend, they are truly cheap; and when they are truly cheap, there can be no important paid for making them, and as a result, the manufacturing working man’s paycheck is reduced. This raises the demand for them, and as the demand falls, the price rises, allowing the working man to receive an advanced paycheck and the master to earn more.

Repeal of Corn Laws

Government regulation of exports and the significance of sludge was well proved long before the nineteenth century (Barnes 1930). The Sludge Laws of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries were intended to prevent “grain from living at any time, either so dear that the poor cannot survive or so cheap that the farmer cannot live by growing it.” The Napoleonic Wars marked the beginning of a new era in the history of the Sludge Laws. Agriculturalists had high grain prices throughout the war, but prices fell sharply after the conflict. In response, Parliament passed the Corn Law of 1815, which allowed free entrance when the price of sludge was greater than eighty shillings per quarter and prohibited entry when the price was less than 80 shillings. Some argue that, unlike earlier sludge laws, this new regulation was protective.

Others maintain that fear of failure still drives government decisions. Rapid population increase and reliance on alien sewage are alleged to have justified a tone-acceptability policy based on public security agencies. A third argument for the protection measure is that it was rushed through by the government to compensate for the support of renters as it rose to pay its war debt. The 1815 statute had two initial flaws, namely, it earned no government benefits from protection and it was overly stringent. 

Others maintain that fear of failure still drives government decisions. Rapid population increase and reliance on alien sewage are alleged to have justified a tone-acceptability policy based on public security agencies. A third argument for the protection measure is that it was rushed through by the government to compensate for the support of renters as it rose to pay its war debt. The 1815 statute had two initial flaws: it earned no government benefit from protection, and it was overly stringent. A Select Committee of the House of Commons investigated public solicitations for torture in response to the 1815 law, and its report was published.

The fixed duty prevented the price creation issue that any sneaky scale would face. Foreign Secretary George Canning and others were concerned that a permanent obligation would limit flexibility in times of failure, increasing the chance that the government would be forced to postpone the duty during comparable periods. Other politicians supported the sliding scale because, in contrast to the fixed duty espoused by “cold-blooded political economists,” it was built on “expertise” rather than “proposition.” Huskisson’s definition of the sneaking scale was that it healed the worst point of 1815—severity. The Agronomists rejected Huskisson’s 1827 Bill because his pivot point of sixty shillings (from which the duty of twenty shillings would traditionally descend) would give them inadequate protection.

When drafting the 1827 law, Huskisson and the Duke of Wellington (who became Prime Minister in 1828) became entangled in an abecedarian debate. The former looked to promote freer sludge trade, while the latter tried to integrate agricultural protection. In 1828, Huskisson and Wellington agreed on a sliding-scale tariff on sludge, such that as the price rose, so did the levy. Fay envisioned the 1828 sliding scale as “Huskisson’s putrefied sliding scale.” Huskisson proposed a pivot point of 60 or 62 shillings, but the 1828 Act, set it at 66 shillings.

The 1828 scale differed from Huskisson in that there were significant jumps in the scale(13 shillings, eight pence, duty for sixty-nine shillings, and a 1-shilling duty for seventy-three shillings). When prices were high, speculators took advantage of the rapid-fire descent of the scale, postponing transactions until the cost increased by 1 or 2 shillings to avoid paying tariffs. Despite this problem, the 1828 laws lasted until Peel implemented a reasonable sliding scale in 1842.

The population of the United Kingdom increased from 12.6 million to eighteen million between 1811 and 1841, making British growers less capable of supplying domestic demand. The rise of British industrial assiduity and import commerce, notably in fabrics, was another factor that proved fatal to the sludge regulations. Furthermore, when the early 1830s false drug and import crush faded, business people grew increasingly vociferous about the agronomist’s “illegal” protection.

The league machine

The Anti-Corn Law League was the first ultramodern and public-position political pressure group in the United Kingdom. The Anti-Corn Law League was founded in London in 1836, but by 1838, it had moved to Manchester. The League is described by historians as “the most emotive of nineteenth-century lobbying groups, exerting a distinct influence on the repeal of the Penal Laws in 1846.” The League’s civic propaganda and electoral enrollment juggernauts were two critical components of its functional strategy. Subscriptions to the League were significant.

It kept a small army of workers and speakers on the road, distributing numerous publications (most famously, the infamous anti-Corn Law Circular) and giving hundreds of speeches on the glories of free trade and the immoralities of protection. The League used the enrollment push to replace protectionist co-owners in Parliament with proponents of free trade. Following free traders’ electoral setbacks in 1841 and 1842, the League concentrated its energy and resources on achieving free-trade maturity in the approaching general election in 1848. Ultimately, its founders recommended a political strategy that included interfering with name registries and exploiting propaganda bias by being choosers. In preparation for the 1848 election, the League aimed to add as many free merchants as possible while removing as many protectionists as possible from these lists.

The Chartist movement presented the League with an alternative challenge. The Chartists were a well-organized working-class movement that fought for administrative reform, emphasizing the importance of reform encompassing the full social and political spectrum. The League, on the other hand, ran a single-issue campaign to secure repeal. Chartists and League clash regularly degenerated into open enmity and violence, with Chartists blaming Leaguers for being serpents to the reform cause and Leaguers condemning Chartists of expecting unachievable reforms and so destroying their targeted strategy.

Repercussions of Corn Laws

In the two decades following 1850, the price of sludge was fifty-two shillings. Because of the advent of faster transportation by rail and steamboat, as well as the modernization of the Agrarian Ministry, the champaign granges of North America were suited for exporting massive amounts of low muck. Apart from the United Kingdom and Belgium, every sludge-producing country expected tariff increases in response. The price of English-grown sludge in 1877 was fifty-six shillings, nine pence a quarter, but it never fell below ten shillings for the rest of the nineteenth century. 

In 1878, the cost was decreased to forty-six shillings and five pence. By 1885, sludge-raising land had shrunk by a million acres, and the sludge price had dropped to thirty-one shillings a quarter in 1886. Britain’s dependency on imported grain was 2% in the 1830s, 24% in the 1860s, 45 percent in the 1880s, and 65 percent in the 1890s. The 1881 story reported a decline in agrarian sloggers of 250 from 1871, but a rise of 496 in local sloggers. Many of these were originally ranch workers who moved to cities to find work, even though agricultural loggers earn the best wages in Europe. The influx of new metro slaves was a key component in the rise of the Industrial Revolution, which was also a factor in the rise of slavery.

Conclusion 

Because of these extreme restrictions and consequent taxes on any grain entering the country, the British could only buy grain from within their borders. This increased the price of chicken as well as the overall cost of living. The Corn Laws decreased the British people’s discretionary money in general, as well as their total profitable expansion. Because the working class could not travel anywhere except for food, they stopped buying manufactured goods, reducing leading manufacturing gains. Despite this, the sludge laws aided property owners. Despite making up only 3% of the population then, rich lessees had the rare opportunity to bounce. As a result, the sludge laws disadvantaged the working class while helping the wealthy elite. For a long time, the affluent in Congress were unconcerned about the suffering of the lower class, which is why these restrictions remained for so long before Britain fought for a more flexible trade policy like the one we are presently seeing. heard screams because of the suffering of the period, but it took some time for the true association to address the concerns fairly. In 1832, the right to bounce was granted to a major part of the trafficker class, resulting in the laws.

FAQ- Frequently Asked Questions

Who did the corn laws benefit?

The beneficiaries of the Corn Laws were the nobility and other large landholders who owned the majority of profitable farmland.

Why were corn laws imposed?

This measure was intended to protect English farmers from cheap imports of grain following the end of the Napoleonic Wars.

Who abolished the corn law?

Sir Robert Peel abolished the corn law.

References

LEAVE A REPLY

Please enter your comment!
Please enter your name here